During a recent discussion with some people on a
different platform, the land reform issue popped up yet again, so this piece
that takes into account all that we’ve discussed amongst ourselves is mostly
for their benefit. I don’t propose to see everything, know everything and have
all the answers, thus I seek a discussion and input from readers; even if it is
only for my own personal development.
If we are to make any sense of why the agrarian reform
system in South Africa is not quite working at the moment, then we must first
attempt to understand the underlying economic and social issues that the industry
faces as they will complicate things as time goes by.
The sheer size
of things
It is an often expressed fact that South Africa has tons
of farmland in the hands of a few wealthy landowners and this issue is beyond
dispute, but what we should clearly understand is that this phenomenon is not
unique in the South African milieu nor is it the work of some mysterious
supremacist faction or force. It has happened due to both a natural and
economic progression.
As any economy shifts focus from the primary
(agriculture, mining, fishing, forestry) economy and into the secondary
(manufacturing) and tertiary (service) economy, there is a natural desire among
younger generations to move along with it, since the new focus implies greater
income and security. The effect this had on the farming industry is that many
children of farmers, especially post 1994, simply did not have any interest in
farming, so when their parents passed away, the farm was simply sold and most
often to existing farmers in the area, thus leading to a growth in the average
size of farms.
The second aspect that requires consideration is the fact
that commercial farming is very much becoming an economy of scale industry. Due
to the frankly massive increases in necessary inputs like fuel (roughly 550% since
2000 at current prices) and electricity (300%+ since 2008) farmers required
ever increasing amounts of farmland in order to continue running profitable
businesses and most small scale commercial farms were simply gobbled up in the
process.
While it may seem an unrelated issue, this truth about
our agrarian sector raises two very real problems for our land reform process. Firstly,
we must keep in mind that the amount of agricultural land we have is finite, so
any attempt form government to buy a large amount of farmland will lead to an
increase in the price of farmland; it is basic economics. The second problem we
must factor in is the fact that much of the infrastructure on previously
smaller farms have fallen into disrepair or have since been demolished because
they take up valuable space. If the large farms are then subdivided among
beneficiaries of the process, they have to be capitalised in terms of housing,
barns, equipment, et cetera in a project of which the cost can easily run into
the hundreds of billions of Rand. This problem is very much a co-determinant of
how fast we can proceed with the restitution project.
We simply do
not have a clue
Another economic factor that further clouds and
complicates the issue of massive commercial farms is the sheer lack of accurate
information we are currently faced with. To my knowledge, there is currently no
way for us to quickly and definitively determine who owns what amount of
farmland; there is no register. Combined with this problem is the fact that we
simply do not know what amount of farmland currently constitutes an economic
unit, i.e. the amount of farmland in a particular area that would allow a
farmer to make a decent living.
The truth is that continuing without this information means
that we are effectively fumbling in the dark and could easily create a
situation where we assign people a piece of farmland that they cannot make a
living on, which would defeat the purpose of the entire exercise.
It is a tricky
business
Commercial farming as a business comes with its own set
of unique challenges, chief among which is the fact that the local market as a
whole has very little power when it comes to setting the price farmers can
expect for their goods. The SAFFEX price reported on the news every day is
primarily determined by what is happening in the mega producing countries like
the USA and Russia, so knowing then to write the futures contract for your
goods is a specialised field on its own. The problem this creates for farmers
is that they have to commit themselves to delivering a set amount of product of
a set quality, but with an unsure outcome; they simply do not know if they will
meet the terms of their contract until harvest day. If they do not, they then
have to pay certain penalties stipulated by the contract. This, of course,
determines the operating capital they have available for the next harvest
season, so if the contract is written at the wrong price, in the wrong quantity
or if some natural element prevents the farmer from meeting his contract, even a
lot of vastly experienced farmers go under in this fashion.
The question here, and I might get lambasted for this, is
how many people who qualify for land restitution (hell, how many people in general)
have the required skills and knowledge to successfully navigate these challenges
and what use is there in restoring them to farmland when there is a large
chance that they do not and would most likely fail? This is, in my view, the
sole reason for almost 80% of all land restitution projects failing or the land
being resold within the first twenty four months of the transfer taking place.
It is very much
socio-historic
Everything else aside, we must always keep in mind that
we are talking about more than just mere assets here; we are talking about the
livelihoods of current landowners who have committed no crimes and the historical
injustices done to claimants. We also know from a debate that’s been raging for
almost as long as we’ve been calling ourselves democratic that this is the
major stumbling block in the entire process and while I will not even attempt
to object to or discredit the social imperative of land restitution the
historic nature of the claims do create an economic problem.
The majority of land claims in the country do not stem
from individuals but from certain tribes that still exist within the broad
South African population and the problem this ultimately creates is that
communal land ownership is very rarely productive as is evident from the
experiences and histories of land restitution in other African countries.
Zambia is a chief example and what their experience has shown is not only the
fact that internal squabbles often leave large tracts of agricultural land
lying fallow, but that you are inevitably faced with a massive skills flight
from the sector, since those with the most recent and up to date skills and
knowledge regarding farming methods, et cetera are no longer within the
industry.
But what about
tomorrow?
The often unspoken fact of the matter is that as a
nation, our food security is already under pressure. Due to economic
considerations, many farmers are making the move from planting seasonal staple
crops like wheat and corn to planting more lucrative permanent crops like
pecans in order to avoid the yearly input costs required by seasonal crops.
Additionally, evidence is beginning to surface that farms along the Vaal River and
lower Oranje River systems (after it joins with the Vaal) are becoming less and
less productive due to the regression in the water quality coming from higher
up in the system. This is primarily due to the poor management of human waste
in municipalities along the upper Vaal River and the increased amount of mine acid
draining into the system.
To this point, we must come to the realisation that this
project can have far more severe consequences for our society via greatly
increased food prices and knock on inflation if we do not proceed with the
utmost circumspection.
So how do we
solve it?
While I am sure that other observers will point out a
myriad of other problems, the ones that I have mentioned seem to be the larger
broad economic problems facing the land reform process in South Africa today, but
ultimately the number one problem with the land reform process has been political
and that’s what needs changing before anything else.
Up until this moment in time, we have cited redress for
historical injustices as our reason for attempting agrarian reform. While I am
not attempting to rewrite or even defend our sordid history, we have to
recognise that this stance immediately clouds the issue since it brings a lot
of emotion and a victim vs. perpetrator orientation into the fold; this also
causes us to dismiss legitimate concerns regarding the system as a victim
mentality or attempts to protect white privilege. It therefore causes all of us
to be on our heels or high horses and talk past one another instead of speaking
with each other. This cannot continue.
I am truly of the opinion that we need to make a mental
shift from historical redress and begin to put agrarian reform forward as a
measure to economically develop our country and our people that will ultimately
also address the societal and economic imbalances caused by our racially
divided past. Once we’ve been able to do this, then sorting out the problems
regarding agrarian reform merely becomes a matter of implementing a few tweaks
to the system and I put forwards the following proposals.
Primarily, we really need to pay attention to our lack of
information, since it hampers our ability to plan this properly. I believe that
we should first find out who owns what land, who has a claim to what land and
how much will be required in order to provide people with a decent living off
the land. This will also go a long way in sifting out all the bullshit that is
currently clouding the issue and when we do take on land restitution afterwards
we can then create private land ownership for the maximum number of individuals
with a reasonable certainty that they will be able to make a decent living as
farmers.
As explained, I am diametrically opposed to the current
system of the wholesale transfer of farmland to communities and it is not only
because of the upwards pressure it puts on land prices, the additional pressure
it places on our food security or the historic inefficiencies of communal
ownership, but also because our budget for this is only so big. By purchasing
the farm over a period of time (say 20% biannually over 10 years or one or two
subdivided plots per year) you not only reduce the pressure on land prices, but
also the impact that would be felt if the project happens to fail, while
greatly increasing the odds that we can salvage projects in the event that they
should fail. Additionally, you have the current farmer, who probably has vast
experience farming in the area, on hand to act in a mentorship role to the
benefit of the emerging farmer, thereby facilitating the transfer of skills from
one generation of farmer to the next.
What should be clear is that there is no use in just replacing
a white farmer with a black owner as we’ve been doing, but that we need to take
steps to ensure that the necessary skills required by commercial farming are transferred
to the new owners of the farm. It is currently estimated that Government owns
about 14% or some 16.8 million hectares of farmland in the country. What we
therefore need to do to ensure a transfer of skills and reduce the odds of the
restitution project failing is to establish agricultural colleges and “proving”
or rather “training” farms tailor made for people with no agricultural
experience on parts of the Government owned land and use the remainder as
possible restitution locations for future land claims in order to boost food
security or merely to speed up the process as this land needs not be bought,
but is readily available.
Since the lack of financial support and economic
pressures in general have been pointed out as problems facing both the industry
and our social imperative in recent years, we not only need to take steps to
ensure that emerging farmers have access to sufficient operating capital and
certain business support services like accountants during the first year or two,
but that our farmers in general are adequately supported financially, as is the
norm in most developed economies in the world. I mean, we can save farmers as much
as 20% of their annual fuel-spend if we simply put a mechanism in place by
which they can reclaim certain levies they pay on fuel from Government or
receive a tax discount for it.
It turned out to be way more than two cents’ worth in the
end, but hey, at least it is out there now and I won't charge you more than a penny.
This is indeed an impressive and comprehensive analysis which will require a bit of reflection before I will comment. What I can say is that there is a massive and indeed frightening divide between your assessment of what is required for successful and sustainable land reform and the popular wisdom at grass root level. I have been putting an ear to the ground by joining social media platform which are sympathetic to the ideology of the EFF. What is clear is that the land hunger is by no meana and perhaps not even primarily only aimed at farm land. There is a great need for Lebensraum among the millions who are trapped in the claustrophobic confines of the squatter camps. And those who are exploited by unscrupulous landlords having to pay rent that they can ill afford. They are asking why they as native Africans have no place to live in the country of their birth? And the opportunists tell them it is because the whites stole the land. And the reaction to this is the familiar slogan of "Africa is for the Africans". This does not mean that there is no interest in farming. Or rather a return to "the good old days" before van Riebeeck where every man farmed for his family and all had enough to eat. This subsistence farming of an earlier age is romanticized and is in a way understandable in the context of unemployment, poverty and hunger which so many have to face on a daily basis. There is also very little understanding or appreciation for the complexities or even the need for commercial farming. How difficult can it be? We farmed before van Riebeeck came and survived. The whites did not teach us to farm. What do we care about food security? We have never had it and we survived. These are all comments that are regularly expressed. There is a massive need for dialogue and dissemination of ideas and information. It need to be done in a way that will not suggest that whites are the only ones capable of successful farming. Neither should it be come across as a smokescreen or excuse for protecting white privilege. The challenge is to have this discussion in an atmosphere of mutual trust and respect. This is exactly what is not happening at this point in time. I am posting as anonymous simply because I am not familiar with this environment and do not know how to identify myself as Herman
ReplyDeleteI completely understand the growing frustration and resentment among the most disenfranchised people in the country, because at the moment they were sold nothing but a pipe dream and empty promise upon empty promise when it comes to the advantages of democracy and a peaceful transition into it, but from a purely economic perspective, the current situation is not at all unexpected.
DeleteI don't know how fluent you are in economics, so I'll try to keep it as simple as possible.
The current situation is the expected result of twenty years of attempted transformation economics and a Government that is wholly unable or unwilling to address the core problem our economy inherited from Apartheid. When you sift through all the political and emotional bullshit, Apartheid left us with an economy that is designed to vastly enrich a small elite on the back of cheap labour provided by a huge un- or semi-educated workforce. This is evident in the erstwhile Bantu Education system and the proven fact that in 1994, only around 15% of black people had at least a completed high school education in comparison with roughly 66% of whites. Fast forward to Census 2011 (my source for this data) and you'll find that this educational disparity mostly remains with 35% of black people having completed at least high school and a number among whites standing at 76%. This is why you still see the structure of Gauteng as it stands today. It is comprised of small, insanely affluent suburbs surrounded by the squalor of massive squatter camps; the poor majority still works for a mere pittance to enrich the small elite and it doesn't really matter what colour they are or if the new elite now find themselves in Government, the big financial houses or as large scale residential or commercial property owners rather than the ivory towers of the mining houses, it is the exact same thing.
If we are to adequately address this we must move away from economic transformation (that has done virtually nothing to solve our problem) and on to economic development, of which my ideas on land reform are but a small part. In it's most basic form economic development requires us to develop the three basic capacities of our economy, i.e. our capacity to deliver finished goods and services, our capacity to deliver a skilled workforce capable of producing it and our capacity to transport these goods and services as cheaply and quickly as possible. You're an engineer so you'll understand that idea that one can only force so much water through a certain width of pipe before the pressure becomes too great and the pipe bursts, this is the same thing. We need to widen all three of our economic pipes.