It’s no secret that I have always been in favour of Agrarian
land reform in principle, but that I have my reservations with the system by which
Government has sought to attain the redistribution. It is also no secret that I
am completely opposed to the EFF’s policy of "overnight" expropriation without
compensation, but I’ve only recently realised that I have never really giving
full voice to why I am opposed to what is effectively the willy-nilly nationalisation
of farmland. For me, there are simply too many unanswered questions surrounding
this particular idea to support it.
Questions of
occupancy
There is currently no system in place where we can quickly
and definitively determine who owns what amount of farmland, so the immediate
problem would be that you create massive uncertainty as to who has the right to
occupy and work the land on behalf of the National Government should
nationalisation ever occur. If we are not able to rapidly make changes to the
occupancy of farmland, then indeed we have made no fundamental change and
coupled with the fact that there is simply no definitive indication as to who
has historical claim to what part and amount of farmland, we instantly create
the very real possibility and prime conditions for the violent land grabs we’ve
seen north of the Limpopo river.
The second question is the method of occupancy and
remuneration of the people that work the land. In Russia for instance, the
state paid people a salary for producing what they were ordered to produce, but
irrespective of the amounts produced. The problem with this particular system,
of course, is that there is simply no motivation for people to produce as much
as possible because it does not determine their remuneration and theft of the
produce, in order to avoid paying higher prices later on, was absolutely rife. This
particular system also creates an absence of any sort of hierarchy, since
everyone is paid the same salary and thus have no authority to tell other
people what to do; people simply do not function as effectively without one
because there will always be the perception of “I have to do everything around
here” that will cause production to suffer.
The alternative, more modern system would be for farmers to
rent the property from the state over the long term (50+ years) and take their
profits as income in the normal fashion, but, as left wing detractors will
argue, this is fundamentally no different from private ownership except for the
fact that the State can place limits on how much land an individual is able or
allowed to rent, while holding very little improvements for the lot of
farmworkers. Capitalist detractors of such a system will no doubt point out
that it opens up the door for large scale abuses by unscrupulous Government
officials, would kill off all private investment in the agricultural sector and
destroy access to credit in the agrarian sector of the economy.
The loss of skills
question
A major argument against the redistribution of land is that
the recipients of the land do not necessarily have the necessary skills to
ensure the successful operation of a farm while the previous owners will simply
leave and take their skills with them. Supporters of the system normally see
this as an insult, but that particular concern is very real and one’s personal
feeling about it does not make it less valid, because with a large scale
transfer of land, there will be some level of skill loss, so it is only prudent
to at least attempt to minimise its impact. It is a sad historical fact of
South African land restitution that as much as 80% of all projects fail or
become unproductive within 24 months of the land transfer taking place and if
this should happen on a national scale, it is something that our economy will
simply not recover from during the lifetime of anyone that happens to read
this. In many other instances, the community is forced to rent the property to
outside operators (often the previous owner) at a mere pittance of what they
could have made if they operated things themselves and this is simply not the
intended purpose of land reform in my opinion.
While many people would undoubtedly see this as yet another
baseless claim that blacks cannot be successful farmers, the intention of this statement
of fact is to serve as an indictment to both the absolute absence of support
systems and the haphazard manner in which land reform has been applied in the
past. The overall goal is not only the transfer of land, but also the skills
necessary to fully exploit it and both of these aspects require serious
investigation before we can attempt land reform in a responsible and
non-destructive manner.
The question of Resources
and Infrastructure
It is common knowledge that the amount of commercial farms
and farmers has seen a steady decline over the past two or three decades due to
both natural and economic considerations, even if there is nothing strange
about this phenomenon. It is a common symptom of an economy that makes the move
from the primary sector and into the secondary or tertiary sectors of the
economy, since they offer bigger professional security and higher income. The
problem created as far as the redistribution of land is concerned is that the
resources and capital goods required for farming existing in the sector has also
been reduced. Yes, it’s only logical that a larger farm would need more
tractors for instance, but only up to a certain point, since more of them would
mean that they are not being used with maximum efficiency. Another aspect not
to be ignored is the fact that necessary structures like housing, barns and
storage space for example, would have become fewer in line with the reduction
in the amount of farms and the same applies to infrastructure where “unnecessary”
infrastructure like roads, water delivery systems and electrical connections
have been removed or allowed to deteriorate into oblivion.
The question thus becomes how the existing resources will be
distributed and how shortages are to be met, because even if the farms are
expropriated without compensation, Government would still be stuck with a
capitalisation bill that could easily run into the billions, if not hundreds of
billions, of Rand. Also, in the event of a total command structure, who will be
responsible for the administration and cost of maintaining the mentioned
equipment and structures? Since they are essentially owned by Government, it is
only logical that Government should shoulder the responsibility, leading to a
massive administrational problem.
The African
experience
The experiences north of our borders since long before
Mandela took his Long Walk to Freedom all show the same result; that it is
highly risky and near economic suicide to attempt such reforms without due
consideration and having iron clad systems in place. The country most on the up
and up after forty years of this system being in place is Zambia and I would
like to discuss their system as a possible model for South African use for a
moment.
After colonisation ended in 1964, the new Republic sought a
land reform project to replace that enforced on the country by the British. The
specific land reforms were announced in the Mulungushi Economic Reforms of 1968
and these included the following:
- all land should be vested in the President of the Republic of Zambia,
- all land under freehold should be converted to leasehold tenure for hundred years,
- land under customary tenure not to be converted into leasehold, and
- land reforms should be directed at improvement of the use of agricultural land
The problems encountered with this policy however was that
the land was often not used productively, that the uncertainty created by the
leasehold structure made it nearly impossible for farmers to access credit and
that the land under customary tenure was poorly administered. A more recent development of this land reform
project is that Zambia no longer possesses people with the necessary skills to
boost agricultural production in the country and the Government realised that
it was time for a new round of land reform. Since then most of the non-tribal
land in Zambia has been under a 99 year leasehold system that automatically
renews upon expiration to overcome the problems with uncertainty of tenure and
a provision was brought that allowed users of customary/tribal lands to obtain
a leasehold on a piece of customary land after due investigation and
consultations with tribal leadership in an attempt to make more efficient use
of tribal agricultural lands.
In the most recent development, however, the Zambian
Government began to actively court Zimbabwean, South African and Namibian commercial
farmers in an attempt to overcome their agri-skills shortage and in their first
year (2011/12) 100 Zimbabwean farmers brought hi-tech farming techniques to the
country and managed to produce 70% of the country’s maize output, thus turning
Zambia from a net importer to a net exporter of food, ironically supplying the
bulk of Zimbabwe’s maize imports. The final changes are that the Zambian
Government is endeavouring to overcome the lack of private investment in
agriculture by providing tax/rent rebates on certain private investments in
agriculture and that a Certificate of Occupancy by the Zambian Government is
now accepted as legal collateral for banks in order to extend credit to farmers
thanks to the automatic renewal of the lease.
What I think
First of all, I don’t favour a total command system since I
think that it would simply be too big of a bureaucratic burden on a State that
thus far seems to fall woefully short in matters of administration. I also
think that we can learn a lot from the Zambian example as system that could be
successfully applied to our situation, but I still do not think that an
overnight change to such a system would be prudent, even if it were possible.
Every instance of land reform in Africa and the modern world
points out the fact that it should be done with the utmost care and
circumspection; adding to our problem is that we not only have different
agricultural regions in the country (dry vs. wet land farming, crops vs.
livestock, et cetera), each of which has different requirements, but that we
are also facing a definite change in climate in most of these regions, thus
rendering traditional crops less productive. So what we need, before we do
anything else, is a complete investigation into four aspects of the process:
- The viability of different crops and livestock in different regions
- The amount of land that would constitute a “living income,” i.e. how much land is required in the different areas that would enable the farmer to make a decent living off the land, otherwise there is simply no point.
- The size, scope and cost of the required capitalisation and infrastructure spend as it would most likely be the biggest determinant of the pace at which land reform can be achieved.
- The total amount of outstanding bonds against agricultural land, because if the land is expropriated, who is responsible for the bond against it? We simply can expect the bank or previous owner to accept responsibility for this, so the responsibility should either fall to the new tenant or Government, since we risk huge losses in the financial system if the bond is merely “written off.”
Finally, a decision must be taken in the historical context;
do we continue with historical land restitution claims as we have been doing or
do we make the available land open to all South Africans who have a
demonstrated will and ability to farm productively? This is perhaps the most
sensitive and emotion laden issue surrounding the entire process, but both the
domestic and international statistics show that tribal or communal tenure of
large tracts of land is simply not as productive as land under individual curatorship.
What we as South Africans from all walks of life and
economic persuasion must realise is that this debate is far from over, but if
the day should arrive that a political organisation has a land reform policy
that answers these (and I’m sure other people will have more) questions to my
satisfaction, then I will most likely support it.